[p.23]
Chapter 3
THE PRINCIPLE OF EFFECTIVE DEMAND
I
We need, to start with, a few terms which will be defined precisely later. In
a given state of technique, resources and costs, the employment of a given
volume of labour by an entrepreneur involves him in two kinds of expense: first
of all, the amounts which he pays out to the factors of production (exclusive of
other entrepreneurs) for their current services, which we shall call the factor
cost of the employment in question; and secondly, the amounts which he pays
out to other entrepreneurs for what he has to purchase from them together with
the sacrifice which he incurs by employing the equipment instead of leaving it
idle, which we shall call the user cost of the employment in question.[1]
The excess of the value of the resulting output over the sum of its factor cost
and its user cost is the profit or, as we shall call it, the income of
the entrepreneur. The factor cost is, of course, the same thing, looked at from
the point of view of the entrepreneur, as what the factors of production regard
as their income. Thus the factor cost and the entrepreneur's profit make up,
between them, what we shall define as the total income resulting from the
employment given by the entrepreneur. The entrepreneur's profit thus defined is,
as it should be, the quantity which he endeavours to maximise when he is
deciding what amount of employ-[p.24]ment to offer. It is sometimes
convenient, when we are looking at it from the entrepreneur's standpoint, to
call the aggregate income (i.e. factor cost plus profit) resulting from a
given amount of employment the proceeds of that employment. On the other
hand, the aggregate supply price [1]
of the output of a given amount of employment is the expectation of proceeds
which will just make it worth the while of the entrepreneurs to give that
employment. [2]
It follows that in a given situation of technique, resources and factor cost
per unit of employment, the amount of employment, both in each individual firm
and industry and in the aggregate, depends on the amount of the proceeds which
the entrepreneurs expect to receive from the corresponding output. [3]
For entrepreneurs will endeavour to fix the amount of employ-[p.25]ment
at the level which they expect to maximise the excess of the proceeds over the
factor cost.
Let Z be the aggregate supply price of the output from employing N
men, the relationship between Z and N being written Z = f(N),
which can be called the Aggregate Supply Function. [1]
Similarly, let D be the proceeds which entrepreneurs expect to receive
from the employment of N men, the relationship between D and N
being written D = f(N), which can be called the Aggregate
Demand Function.
Now if for a given value of N the expected proceeds are greater than
the aggregate supply price, i.e. if D is greater than Z,
there will be an incentive to entrepreneurs to increase employment beyond N
and, if necessary, to raise costs by competing with one another for the factors
of production, up to the value of N for which Z has become equal
to D. Thus the volume of employment is given by the point of intersection
between the aggregate demand function and the aggregate supply function; for it
is at this point that the entrepreneurs' expectation of profits will be
maximised. The value of D at the point of the aggregate demand function,
where it is intersected by the aggregate supply function, will be called the
effective demand. Since this is the substance of the General Theory of
Employment, which it will be our object to expound, the succeeding chapters will
be largely occupied with examining the various factors upon which these two
functions depend.
The classical doctrine, on the other hand, which used to be expressed
categorically in the statement that "Supply creates its own Demand"
and continues to underlie all orthodox economic theory, involves a special
assumption as to the relationship between these two functions. For "Supply
creates its own Demand" [p.26] must mean that f(N)
and f(N) are equal for all values of N,
i.e. for all levels of output and employment; and that when there is an
increase in Z( = f(N))
corresponding to an increase in N, D( = f(N))
necessarily increases by the same amount as Z. The classical theory
assumes, in other words, that the aggregate demand price (or proceeds) always
accommodates itself to the aggregate supply price; so that, whatever the value
of N may be, the proceeds D assume a value equal to the aggregate
supply price Z which corresponds to N. That is to say, effective
demand, instead of having a unique equilibrium value, is an infinite range of
values all equally admissible; and the amount of employment is indeterminate
except in so far as the marginal disutility of labour sets an upper limit.
If this were true, competition between entrepreneurs would always lead to an
expansion of employment up to the point at which the supply of output as a whole
ceases to be elastic, i.e. where a further increase in the value of the
effective demand will no longer be accompanied by any increase in output.
Evidently this amounts to the same thing as full employment. In the previous
chapter we have given a definition of full employment in terms of the behaviour
of labour. An alternative, though equivalent, criterion is that at which we have
now arrived, namely a situation in which aggregate employment is inelastic in
response to an increase in the effective demand for its output. Thus Say's law,
that the aggregate demand price of output as a whole is equal to its aggregate
supply price for all volumes of output, is equivalent to the proposition that
there is no obstacle to full employment. If, however, this is not the true law
relating the aggregate demand and supply functions, there is a vitally important
chapter of economic theory which remains to be written and without which all
discussions concerning the volume of aggregate employment are futile. [p.27]
II
A brief summary of the theory of employment to be worked out in the course of
the following chapters may, perhaps, help the reader at this stage, even though
it may not be fully intelligible. The terms involved will be more carefully
defined in due course. In this summary we shall assume that the money-wage and
other factor costs are constant per unit of labour employed. But this
simplification, with which we shall dispense later, is introduced solely to
facilitate the exposition. The essential character of the argument is precisely
the same whether or not money-wages, etc., are liable to change.
The outline of our theory can be expressed as follows. When employment
increases, aggregate real income is increased. The psychology of the community
is such that when aggregate real income is increased aggregate consumption is
increased, but not by so much as income. Hence employers would make a loss if
the whole of the increased employment were to be devoted to satisfying the
increased demand for immediate consumption. Thus, to justify any given amount of
employment there must be an amount of current investment sufficient to absorb
the excess of total output over what the community chooses to consume when
employment is at the given level. For unless there is this amount of investment,
the receipts of the entrepreneurs will be less than is required to induce them
to offer the given amount of employment. It follows, therefore, that, given what
we shall call the community's propensity to consume, the equilibrium level of
employment, i.e. the level at which there is no inducement to employers
as a whole either to expand or to contract employment, will depend on the amount
of current investment. The amount of current investment will depend, in turn, on
what we shall call the inducement to invest; and the inducement to invest will [p.28]
be found to depend on the relation between the schedule of the marginal
efficiency of capital and the complex of rates of interest on loans of various
maturities and risks.
Thus, given the propensity to consume and the rate of new investment, there
will be only one level of employment consistent with equilibrium; since any
other level will lead to inequality between the aggregate supply price of output
as a whole and its aggregate demand price. This level cannot be greater than
full employment, i.e. the real wage cannot be less than the marginal
disutility of labour. But there is no reason in general for expecting it to be equal
to full employment. The effective demand associated with full employment is
a special case, only realised when the propensity to consume and the inducement
to invest stand in a particular relationship to one another. This particular
relationship, which corresponds to the assumptions of the classical theory, is
in a sense an optimum relationship. But it can only exist when, by accident or
design, current investment provides an amount of demand just equal to the excess
of the aggregate supply price of the output resulting from full employment over
what the community will choose to spend on consumption when it is fully
employed.
This theory can be summed up in the following propositions:
(1) In a given situation of technique, resources and costs, income
(both money-income and real income) depends on the volume of employment N.
(2) The relationship between the community's income and what it
can be expected to spend on consumption, designated by D1,
will depend on the psychological characteristic of the community, which we shall
call its propensity to consume. That is to say, consumption will depend
on the level of aggregate income and, therefore, on the level of employment N,
except when there is some change in the propensity to consume. [p.29]
(3) The amount of labour N which the entrepreneurs decide
to employ depends on the sum (D) of two quantities, namely D1,
the amount which the community is expected to spend on consumption, and D2,
the amount which it is expected to devote to new investment. D is what we
have called above the effective demand.
(4) Since D1 + D2 = D = f(N),
where f is the aggregate supply function, and since,
as we have seen in (2) above, D1 is a function of N,
which we may write c(N), depending on the
propensity to consume, it follows that f(N) - c(N) = D2.
(5) Hence the volume of employment in equilibrium depends on (i)
the aggregate supply function, f, (ii) the propensity
to consume, c, and (iii) the volume of investment, D2.
This is the essence of the General Theory of Employment.
(6) For every value of N there is a corresponding marginal
productivity of labour in the wage-goods industries; and it is this which
determines the real wage. (5) is, therefore, subject to the condition that N
cannot exceed the value which reduces the real wage to equality with the
marginal disutility of labour. This means that not all changes in D are
compatible with our temporary assumption that money-wages are constant. Thus it
will be essential to a full statement of our theory to dispense with this
assumption.
(7) On the classical theory, according to which D = f(N)
for all values of N, the volume of employment is in neutral
equilibrium for all values of N less than its maximum value; so that the
forces of competition between entrepreneurs may be expected to push it to this
maximum value. Only at this point, on the classical theory, can there be stable
equilibrium.
(8) When employment increases, D1 will
increase, but not by so much as D; since when our income increases our
consumption increases also, but not by so much. The key to our practical problem
is to be found in this [p.30] psychological law. For it follows from this
that the greater the volume of employment the greater will be the gap between
the aggregate supply price (Z) of the corresponding output and the sum (D1)
which the entrepreneurs can expect to get back out of the expenditure of
consumers. Hence, if there is no change in the propensity to consume, employment
cannot increase, unless at the same time D2 is increasing so
as to fill the increasing gap between Z and D1. Thus¾except
on the special assumptions of the classical theory according to which there is
some force in operation which, when employment increases, always causes D2
to increase sufficiently to fill the widening gap between Z and D1¾the
economic system may find itself in stable equilibrium with N at a level
below full employment, namely at the level given by the intersection of the
aggregate demand function with the aggregate supply function.
Thus the volume of employment is not determined by the marginal disutility of
labour measured in terms of real wages, except in so far as the supply of labour
available at a given real wage sets a maximum level to employment. The
propensity to consume and the rate of new investment determine between them the
volume of employment, and the volume of employment is uniquely related to a
given level of real wages¾not the other way round.
If the propensity to consume and the rate of new investment result in a
deficient effective demand, the actual level of employment will fall short of
the supply of labour potentially available at the existing real wage, and the
equilibrium real wage will be greater than the marginal disutility of the
equilibrium level of employment.
This analysis supplies us with an explanation of the paradox of poverty in
the midst of plenty. For the mere existence of an insufficiency of effective
demand may, and often will, bring the increase of employment to a standstill before
a level of full employ-[p.31]ment has been reached. The insufficiency of
effective demand will inhibit the process of production in spite of the fact
that the marginal product of labour still exceeds in value the marginal
disutility of employment.
Moreover the richer the community, the wider will tend to be the gap between
its actual and its potential production; and therefore the more obvious and
outrageous the defects of the economic system. For a poor community will be
prone to consume by far the greater part of its output, so that a very modest
measure of investment will be sufficient to provide full employment; whereas a
wealthy community will have to discover much ampler opportunities for investment
if the saving propensities of its wealthier members are to be compatible with
the employment of its poorer members. If in a potentially wealthy community the
inducement to invest is weak, then, in spite of its potential wealth, the
working of the principle of effective demand will compel it to reduce its actual
output, until, in spite of its potential wealth, it has become so poor that its
surplus over its consumption is sufficiently diminished to correspond to the
weakness of the inducement to invest.
But worse still. Not only is the marginal propensity to consume [1]
weaker in a wealthy community, but, owing to its accumulation of capital being
already larger, the opportunities for further investment are less attractive
unless the rate of interest falls at a sufficiently rapid rate; which 'brings us
to the theory of the rate of interest and to the reasons why it does not
automatically fall to the appropriate level, which will occupy Book IV.
Thus the analysis of the Propensity to Consume, the definition of the
Marginal Efficiency of Capital and the theory of the Rate of Interest are the
three main gaps in our existing knowledge which it will be necessary to fill.
When this has been accomplished, [p.32] we shall find that the theory of
prices falls into its proper place as a matter which is subsidiary to our
general theory. We shall discover, however, that money plays an essential part
in our theory of the rate of interest; and we shall attempt to disentangle the
peculiar characteristics of money which distinguish it from other things.
III
The idea that we can safely neglect the aggregate demand function is
fundamental to the Ricardian
economics, which underlie what we have been taught for more than a century. Malthus,
indeed, had vehemently opposed Ricardo's
doctrine that it was impossible for effective demand to be deficient; but
vainly. For, since Malthus was unable to explain clearly (apart from an appeal
to the facts of common observation) how and why effective demand could be
deficient or excessive, he failed to furnish an alternative construction; and
Ricardo conquered England as completely as the Holy Inquisition conquered Spain.
Not only was his theory accepted by the city, by statesmen and by the academic
world. But controversy ceased; the other point of view completely disappeared;
it ceased to be discussed. The great puzzle of Effective Demand with which
Malthus had wrestled vanished from economic literature. You will not find it
mentioned even once in the whole works of Marshall,
Edgeworth and Professor Pigou,
from whose hands the classical theory has received its most mature embodiment.
It could only live on furtively, below the surface, in the underworlds of Karl Marx,
Silvio Gesell or Major Douglas.
The completeness of the Ricardian victory is something of a curiosity and a
mystery. It must have been due to a complex of suitabilities in the doctrine to
the environment into which it was projected. That it [p.33] reached
conclusions quite different from what the ordinary uninstructed person would
expect, added, I suppose, to its intellectual prestige. That its teaching,
translated into practice, was austere and often unpalatable, lent it virtue.
That it was adapted to carry a vast and consistent logical superstructure, gave
it beauty. That it could explain much social injustice and apparent cruelty as
an inevitable incident in the scheme of progress, and the attempt to change such
things as likely on the whole to do more harm than good, commended it to
authority. That it afforded a measure of justification to the free activities of
the individual capitalist, attracted to it the support of the dominant social
force behind authority.
But although the doctrine itself has remained unquestioned by orthodox
economists up to a late date, its signal failure for purposes of scientific
prediction has greatly impaired, in the course of time, the prestige of its
practitioners. For professional economists, after Malthus, were apparently
unmoved by the lack of correspondence between the results of their theory and
the facts of observation;¾a discrepancy which the
ordinary man has not failed to observe, with the result of his growing
unwillingness to accord to economists that measure of respect which he gives to
other groups of scientists whose theoretical results are confirmed by
observation when they are applied to the facts.
The celebrated optimism of traditional economic theory, which has led
to economists being looked upon as Candides, who, having left this world for the
cultivation of their gardens, teach that all is for the best in the best of all
possible worlds provided we will let well alone, is also to be traced, I think,
to their having neglected to take account of the drag on prosperity which can be
exercised by an insufficiency of effective demand. For there would obviously be
a natural tendency towards the optimum employment of resources in a Society
which was functioning after the [p.34] manner of the classical
postulates. It may well be that the classical theory represents the way in which
we should like our Economy to behave. But to assume that it actually does so is
to assume our difficulties away.
Footnotes: [p. 23] 1 - A
precise definition of user cost will be given in Chapter
6. [back to text]
[p. 24] 1 - Not to be confused (vide
infra) with the supply price of a unit of output in the ordinary sense of
this term. [back to text]
[p. 24] 2 - The reader will observe
that I am deducting the user cost both from the proceeds and from the aggregate
supply price of a given volume of output, so that both these terms are to be
interpreted net of user cost; whereas the aggregate sum paid by the
purchasers are, of course, gross of user cost. The reasons
why this is convenient will be given in Chapter 6.
The essential point is that the aggregate proceeds and aggregate supply price
net of user cost can be defined uniquely and unambiguously; whereas, since user
cost is obviously dependent both on the degree of integration of industry and on
the extent to which entrepreneurs buy from one another, there can be no
definition of the aggregate sums paid by purchasers, inclusive of user
cost, which is independent of these factors. There is a similar difficulty
even in defining supply price in the ordinary sense for an individual producer;
and in the case of the aggregate supply price of output as a whole
serious difficulties of duplication are involved, which have not always been
faced. If the term is to be interpreted gross of user cost, they can only
be overcome by making special assumptions relating to the integration of
entrepreneurs in groups according as they produce consumption-goods or
capital-goods, which are obscure and complicated in themselves and do not
correspond with the facts. If, however, aggregate supply price is defined
as above net of user cost, these difficulties do not arise. The
reader is advised, however, to await the fuller discussion in Chapter
6 and its appendix. [back to text]
[p. 24] 3 - An entrepreneur, who
has to reach a practical decision as to his scale of production, does not, of
course, entertain a single undoubting expectation of what the sale-proceeds of a
given output will be, but several hypothetical expectations held with varying
degrees of probability and definiteness. By his expectations of proceeds I
mean, therefore, that expectation of proceeds which, if it were held with
certainty, would lead to the same behaviour as does the bundle of vague and more
various possibilities which actually makes up his state of expectation when he
reaches his decision. [back to text]
[p.25] 1 - In Chapter 20
a function closely related to the above will be called the employment function. [back
to text] [p.31] 1 - Defined in Chapter
10, below. [back to text]
|