[p.133]
BOOK IV
THE INDUCEMENT TO INVEST
_____________________________________________________________
[p.135]
Chapter 11
THE MARGINAL EFFICIENCY OF CAPITAL
I
When a man buys an investment or capital-asset, he purchases the right to the
series of prospective returns, which he expects to obtain from selling its
output, after deducting the running expenses of obtaining that output, during
the life of the asset. This series of annuities Q 1 , Q
2 , . . . Q n it is
convenient to call the prospective yield of the investment.
Over against the prospective yield of the investment we have the supply
price of the capital-asset, meaning by this, not the market-price at which
an asset of the type in question can actually be purchased in the market, but
the price which would just induce a manufacturer newly to produce an additional
unit of such assets, i.e. what is sometimes called its replacement cost .
The relation between the prospective yield of a capital-asset and its supply
price or replacement cost, i.e. the relation between the prospective
yield of one more unit of that type of capital and the cost of producing that
unit, furnishes us with the marginal efficiency of capital of that type.
More precisely, I define the marginal efficiency of capital as being equal to
that rate of discount which would make the present value of the series of
annuities given by the returns expected from the capital-asset during its life
just equal to its supply price. This gives us the marginal efficiencies of
particular types of capital-assets. The greatest of [p.136] these
marginal efficiencies can then be regarded as the marginal efficiency of capital
in general.
The reader should note that the marginal efficiency of capital is here
defined in terms of the expectation of yield and of the current supply
price of the capital-asset. It depends on the rate of return expected to be
obtainable on money if it were invested in a newly produced asset; not on
the historical result of what an investment has yielded on its original cost if
we look back on its record after its life is over.
If there is an increased investment in any given type of capital during any
period of time, the marginal efficiency of that type of capital will diminish as
the investment in it is increased, partly because the prospective yield will
fall as the supply of that type of capital is increased, and partly because, as
a rule, pressure on the facilities for producing that type of capital will cause
its supply price to increase; the second of these factors being usually the more
important in producing equilibrium in the short run, but the longer the period
in view the more does the first factor take its place. Thus for each type of
capital we can build up a schedule, showing by how much investment in it will
have to increase within the period, in order that its marginal efficiency should
fall to any given figure. We can then aggregate these schedules for all the
different types of capital, so as to provide a schedule relating the rate of
aggregate investment to the corresponding marginal efficiency of capital in
general which that rate of investment will establish. We shall call this the
investment demand-schedule; or, alternatively, the schedule of the marginal
efficiency of capital.
Now it is obvious that the actual rate of current investment will be pushed
to the point where there is no longer any class of capital-asset of which the
marginal efficiency exceeds the current rate of interest. In other words, the
rate of investment will be pushed to the [p.137] point on the investment
demand-schedule where the marginal efficiency of capital in general is equal to
the market rate of interest. [1]
The same thing can also be expressed as follows. If Qr is
the prospective yield from an asset at time r , and d r is
the present value of £1 deferred r years at the current rate of
interest, S Qr dr
is the demand price of the investment; and investment will be carried
to the point where S Qr dr
becomes equal to the supply price of the investment as defined above.
If, on the other hand, S Qr dr
falls short of the supply price, there will be no current investment
in the asset in question.
It follows that the inducement to invest depends partly on the investment
demand-schedule and partly on the rate of interest. Only at the conclusion
of Book IV will it be possible to take a comprehensive view of the factors
determining the rate of investment in their actual complexity. I would, however,
ask the reader to note at once that neither the knowledge of an asset's
prospective yield nor the knowledge of the marginal efficiency of the asset
enables us to deduce either the rate of interest or the present value of the
asset. We must ascertain the rate of interest from some other source, and only
then can we value the asset by "capitalising" its prospective yield.
II
How is the above definition of the marginal efficiency of capital related to
common usage? The Marginal Productivity or Yield or Efficiency or
Utility of Capital are familiar terms which we have all frequently used.
But it is not easy by searching the literature of economics to [p.138]
find a clear statement of what economists have usually intended by these terms.
There are at least three ambiguities to clear up. There is, to begin with,
the ambiguity whether we are concerned with the increment of physical product
per unit of time due to the employment of one more physical unit of capital, or
with the increment of value due to the employment of one more value unit of
capital. The former involves difficulties as to the definition of the physical
unit of capital, which I believe to be both insoluble and unnecessary. It is, of
course, possible to say that ten labourers will raise more wheat from a given
area when they are in a position to make use of certain additional machines; but
I know no means of reducing this to an intelligible arithmetical ratio which
does not bring in values. Nevertheless many discussions of this subject seem to
be mainly concerned with the physical productivity of capital in some sense,
though the writers fail to make themselves clear.
Secondly, there is the question whether the marginal efficiency of capital is
some absolute quantity or a ratio. The contexts in which it is used and the
practice of treating it as being of the same dimension as the rate of interest
seem to require that it should be a ratio. Yet it is not usually made clear what
the two terms of the ratio are supposed to be.
Finally, there is the distinction, the neglect of which has been the main
cause of confusion and misunderstanding, between the increment of value
obtainable by using an additional quantity of capital in the existing situation,
and the series of increments which it is expected to obtain over the whole
life of the additional capital asset; ¾ i.e. the
distinction between Q1 and the complete series Q1 ,
Q2 , . . . Qr , . . . .This
involves the whole question of the place of expectation in economic theory. Most
discussions of the marginal efficiency of capital seem to pay no attention to
any member of the series except Q1 . Yet this cannot be [p.139]
legitimate except in a static theory, for which all the Q's are equal.
The ordinary theory of distribution, where it is assumed that capital is getting
now its marginal productivity (in some sense or other), is only valid in
a stationary state. The aggregate current return to capital has no direct
relationship to its marginal efficiency; whilst its current return at the margin
of production (i.e. the return to capital which enters into the supply
price of output) is its marginal user cost, which also has no close connection
with its marginal efficiency.
There is, as I have said above, a remarkable lack of any clear account of the
matter. At the same time I believe that the definition which I have given above
is fairly close to what Marshall
intended to mean by the term. The phrase which Marshall himself uses is
"marginal net efficiency" of a factor of production; or,
alternatively, the "marginal utility of capital". The following is a
summary of the most relevant passage which I can find in his Principles
(6th
ed. pp. 519 - 520). I have run together some
non-consecutive sentences to convey the gist of what he says:
"In a certain factory an extra £100 worth of machinery can be applied
so as not to involve any other extra expense, and so as to add annually £3
worth to the net output of the factory after allowing for its own wear and
tear. If the investors of capital push it into every occupation in which it
seems likely to gain a high reward; and if, after this has been done and
equilibrium has been found, it still pays and only just pays to employ this
machinery, we can infer from this fact that the yearly rate of interest is 3
per cent. But illustrations of this kind merely indicate part of the action of
the great causes which govern value. They cannot be made into a theory of
interest, any more than into a theory of wages, without reasoning in a circle. . .
Suppose that the rate of interest is 3 per cent. per annum on perfectly good
security; and that the hat-making trade absorbs a capital of one million
pounds. This implies that the hat-making trade can turn the whole million
pounds' worth of capital to so good account that they would pay 3 per cent.
per annum net for the [p.140] use of it rather than go without any of
it. There may be machinery which the trade would have refused to dispense with
if the rate of interest had been 20 per cent. per annum. If the rate had been
10 per cent., more would have been used; if it had been 6 per cent., still
more; if 4 per cent. still more; and finally, the rate being 3 per cent., they
use more still. When they have this amount, the marginal utility of the
machinery, i.e. the utility of that machinery which it is only just
worth their while to employ, is measured by 3 per cent."
It is evident from the above that Marshall was well aware that we are
involved in a circular argument if we try to determine along these lines what
the rate of interest actually is.[1] In
this passage he appears to accept the view set forth above, that the rate of
interest determines the point to which new investment will be pushed, given the
schedule of the marginal efficiency of capital. If the rate of interest is 3 per
cent, this means that no one will pay £100 for a machine unless he hopes
thereby to add £3 to his annual net output after allowing for costs and
depreciation. But we shall see in Chapter 14 that in
other passages Marshall was less cautious ¾ though
still drawing back when his argument was leading him on to dubious ground.
Although he does not call it the "marginal efficiency of capital",
Professor Irving Fisher has given in his
Theory of Interest (1930) a definition of what he calls "the rate of
return over cost" which is identical with my definition. "The rate of
return over cost", he writes,[2]
"is that rate which, employed in computing the present worth of all the
costs and the present worth of all the returns, will make these two equal."
Professor Fisher explains that the extent of investment in any direction will
depend on a comparison between the rate of return over cost and the rate of
interest. To induce new investment "the rate of return over cost [p.141]
must exceed the rate of interest".[1]
"This new magnitude (or factor) in our study plays the central rôle on the
investment opportunity side of interest theory."[2]
Thus Professor Fisher uses his "rate of return over cost" in the same
sense and for precisely the same purpose as I employ "the marginal
efficiency of capital".
III
The most important confusion concerning the meaning and significance of the
marginal efficiency of capital has ensued on the failure to see that it depends
on the prospective yield of capital, and not merely on its current yield.
This can be best illustrated by pointing out the effect on the marginal
efficiency of capital of an expectation of changes in the prospective cost of
production, whether these changes are expected to come from changes in labour
cost, i.e. in the wage-unit, or from inventions and new technique. The
output from equipment produced to-day will have to compete, in the course of its
life, with the output from equipment produced subsequently, perhaps at a lower
labour cost, perhaps by an improved technique, which is content with a lower
price for its output and will be increased in quantity until the price of its
output has fallen to the lower figure with which it is content. Moreover, the
entrepreneur's profit (in terms of money) from equipment, old or new, will be
reduced, if all output comes to be produced more cheaply. In so far as such
developments are foreseen as probable, or even as possible, the marginal
efficiency of capital produced to-day is appropriately diminished.
This is the factor through which the expectation of changes in the value of
money influences the volume of current output. The expectation of a fall in the
value of money stimulates investment, and hence employment generally, because it
raises the schedule of the [p.142] marginal efficiency of capital, i.e.
the investment demand-schedule; and the expectation of a rise in the value of
money is depressing, because it lowers the schedule of the marginal efficiency
of capital.
This is the truth which lies behind Professor Irving Fisher's
theory of what he originally called "Appreciation and Interest" ¾
the distinction between the money rate of interest and the real rate of
interest where the latter is equal to the former after correction for changes in
the value of money. It is difficult to make sense of this theory as stated,
because it is not clear whether the change in the value of money is or is not
assumed to be foreseen. There is no escape from the dilemma that, if it is not
foreseen, there will be no effect on current affairs; whilst, if it is foreseen,
the prices of existing goods will be forthwith so adjusted that the advantages
of holding money and of holding goods are again equalised, and it will be too
late for holders of money to gain or to suffer a change in the rate of interest
which will offset the prospective change during the period of the loan in the
value of the money lent. For the dilemma is not successfully escaped by
Professor Pigou's expedient of supposing
that the prospective change in the value of money is foreseen by one set of
people but not foreseen by another.
The mistake lies in supposing that it is the rate of interest on which
prospective changes in the value of money will directly react, instead of the
marginal efficiency of a given stock of capital. The prices of existing assets
will always adjust themselves to changes in expectation concerning the
prospective value of money. The significance of such changes in expectation lies
in their effect on the readiness to produce new assets through their
reaction on the marginal efficiency of capital. The stimulating effect of the
expectation of higher prices is due, not to its raising the rate of interest
(that would be a paradoxical way of stimulating output ¾ in
so far as the rate of interest rises, the [p.143] stimulating effect is
to that extent offset), but to its raising the marginal efficiency of a given
stock of capital. If the rate of interest were to rise pari passu with
the marginal efficiency of capital, there would be no stimulating effect from
the expectation of rising prices. For the stimulus to output depends on the
marginal efficiency of a given stock of capital rising relatively to the
rate of interest. Indeed Professor Fisher's theory could be best re-written in
terms of a "real rate of interest" defined as being the rate of interest which
would have to rule, consequently on a change in the state of expectation as to
the future value of money, in order that this change should have no effect on
current output.[1]
It is worth noting that an expectation of a future fall in the rate of
interest will have the effect of lowering the schedule of the marginal
efficiency of capital; since it means that the output from equipment produced
to-day will have to compete during part of its life with the output from
equipment which is content with a lower return. This expectation will have no
great depressing effect, since the expectations, which are held concerning the
complex of rates of interest for various terms which will rule in the future,
will be partially reflected in the complex of rates of interest which rule
to-day. Nevertheless there may be some depressing effect, since the output from
equipment produced to-day, which will emerge towards the end of the life of this
equipment, may have to compete with the output of much younger equipment which
is content with a lower return because of the lower rate of interest which rules
for periods subsequent to the end of the life of equipment produced to-day.
It is important to understand the dependence of the marginal efficiency of a
given stock of capital on changes in expectation, because it is chiefly this
depend-[p.144]ence which renders the marginal efficiency of capital
subject to the somewhat violent fluctuations which are the explanation of the
Trade Cycle. In Chapter 22 below we shall show that the
succession of Boom and Slump can be described and analysed in terms of the
fluctuations of the marginal efficiency of capital relatively to the rate of
interest.
IV
Two types of risk affect the volume of investment which have not commonly
been distinguished, but which it is important to distinguish. The first is the
entrepreneur's or borrower's risk and arises out of doubts in his own mind as to
the probability of his actually earning the prospective yield for which he
hopes. If a man is venturing his own money, this is the only risk which is
relevant.
But where a system of borrowing and lending exists, by which I mean the
granting of loans with a margin of real or personal security, a second type of
risk is relevant which we may call the lender's risk. This may be due either to
moral hazard, i.e. voluntary default or other means of escape, possibly
lawful, from the fulfilment of the obligation, or to the possible insufficiency
of the margin of security, i.e. involuntary default due to the
disappointment of expectation. A third source of risk might be added, namely, a
possible adverse change in the value of the monetary standard which renders a
money-loan to this extent less secure than a real asset; though all or most of
this should be already reflected, and therefore absorbed, in the price of
durable real assets.
Now the first type of risk is, in a sense, a real social cost, though
susceptible to diminution by averaging as well as by an increased accuracy of
foresight. The second, however, is a pure addition to the cost of investment
which would not exist if the borrower and lender were the same person. Moreover,
it involves in part [p.145] a duplication of a proportion of the entrepreneur's risk,
which is added twice to the pure rate of interest to give the minimum
prospective yield which will induce the investment. For if a venture is a risky
one, the borrower will require a wider margin between his expectation of yield
and the rate of interest at which he will think it worth his while to borrow;
whilst the very same reason will lead the lender to require a wider margin
between what he charges and the pure rate of interest in order to induce him to
lend (except where the borrower is so strong and wealthy that he is in a
position to offer an exceptional margin of security). The hope of a very
favourable outcome, which may balance the risk in the mind of the borrower, is
not available to solace the lender.
This duplication of allowance for a portion of the risk has not hitherto been
emphasised, so far as I am aware; but it may be important in certain
circumstances. During a boom the popular estimation of the magnitude of both
these risks, both borrower's risk and lender's risk, is apt to become unusually
and imprudently low.
V
The schedule of the marginal efficiency of capital is of fundamental
importance because it is mainly through this factor (much more than through the
rate of interest) that the expectation of the future influences the present. The
mistake of regarding the marginal efficiency of capital primarily in terms of
the current yield of capital equipment, which would be correct only in
the static state where there is no changing future to influence the present, has
had the result of breaking the theoretical link between to-day and to-morrow.
Even the rate of interest is, virtually, [1]
a [p.146] current phenomenon; and if we reduce the marginal
efficiency of capital to the same status, we cut ourselves off from taking any
direct account of the influence of the future in our analysis of the existing
equilibrium.
The fact that the assumptions of the static state often underlie present-day
economic theory, imports into it a large element of unreality. But the
introduction of the concepts of user cost and of the marginal efficiency of
capital, as defined above, will have the effect, I think, of bringing it back to
reality, whilst reducing to a minimum the necessary degree of adaptation.
It is by reason of the existence of durable equipment that the economic
future is linked to the present. It is, therefore, consonant with, and agreeable
to, our broad principles of thought, that the expectation of the future should
affect the present through the demand price for durable equipment.
Footnotes: [p.137] 1 -
For the sake of simplicity of statement I have slurred the point that we are
dealing with complexes of rates of interest and discount corresponding to the
different lengths of time which will elapse before the various prospective
returns from the asset are realised. But it is not difficult to re-state
the argument so as to cover this point. [back to text]
[p.140] 1 - But was he not wrong in
supposing that the marginal productivity theory of wages was equally circular? [back to text]
[p.140] 2 - Op. cit. p.168. [back to text]
[p.141] 1 - Op. cit.
p.159. [back to text]
[p.142] 2 - Op. cit.
p.155. [back to text]
[p.143] 1 - Cf. Mr. Robertson's
article on "Industrial Fluctuations and the Natural Rate of Interest",
Economic Journal, December, 1934.. [back to text]
[p.145] 1 - Not completely; for
its value partly reflects the uncertainty of the future. Moreover,
the relation between the rates of interest for different terms depends on
expectations. [back to text]
|