[p.87]
BOOK III
THE PROPENSITY TO CONSUME
_____________________________________________________________
[p.89]
Chapter 8
THE PROPENSITY TO CONSUME:
I. The Objective Factors
I
We are now in a position to return to our main theme, from
which we broke off at the end of Book I in order to deal with
certain general problems of method and definition. The ultimate
object of our analysis is to discover what determines the volume
of employment. So far we have established the preliminary
conclusion that the volume of employment is determined by the
point of intersection of the aggregate supply function with the
aggregate demand function. The aggregate supply function,
however, which depends in the main on the physical conditions of
supply, involves few considerations which are not already
familiar. The form may be unfamiliar but the underlying factors
are not new. We shall return to the aggregate supply function in Chapter
20, where we discuss its inverse under the name of the employment
function. But, in the main, it is the part played by the
aggregate demand function which has been overlooked; and it is to
the aggregate demand function that we shall devote Books III and IV.
The aggregate demand function relates any given level of
employment to the "proceeds" which that level of employment is
expected to realise. The "proceeds" are made up of the sum of two
quantities¾the sum which will be
spent on consumption when employment is at the given level, and
the sum which will be devoted [p.90] to investment. The factors which govern these two quantities
are largely distinct. In this book we shall consider the former,
namely what factors determine the sum which will be spent on
consumption when employment is at a given level; and in Book
IV.
we shall proceed to the factors which determine the sum which
will be devoted to investment.
Since we are here concerned in determining what sum will be
spent on consumption when employment is at a given level, we
should, strictly speaking, consider the function which relates
the former quantity (C) to the latter (N). It is
more convenient, however, to work in terms of a slightly
different function, namely, the function which relates the
consumption in terms of wage-units (Cw)
to the income in terms of wage-units (Yw)
corresponding to a level of employment N. This suffers
from the objection that Yw is not a
unique function of N, which is the same in all
circumstances. For the relationship between Yw
and N may depend (though probably in a very minor degree)
on the precise nature of the employment. That is to say, two
different distributions of a given aggregate employment N between
different employments might (owing to the different shapes of the
individual employment functions¾a
matter to be discussed in Chapter 20 below) lead to different
values of Yw. In conceivable
circumstances a special allowance might have to be made for this
factor. But in general it is a good approximation to regard Yw
as uniquely determined by N. We will therefore define what
we shall call the propensity to consume as the functional
relationship c between Yw, a given level of
income in terms of wage-units, and Cw
the expenditure on consumption out of that level of income, so
that
Cw = c(Yw) or C = W·c(Yw).
The amount that the community spends on consumption obviously
depends (i) partly on the amount [p.91] of its income, (ii) partly on the other objective attendant
circumstances, and (iii) partly on the subjective needs and the
psychological propensities and habits of the individuals
composing it and the principles on which the income is divided
between them (which may suffer modification as output is
increased). The motives to spending interact and the attempt to
classify them runs the danger of false division. Nevertheless it
will clear our minds to consider them separately under two broad
heads which we shall call the subjective factors and the
objective factors. The subjective factors, which we shall
consider in more detail in the next Chapter, include those
psychological characteristics of human nature and those social
practices and institutions which, though not unalterable, are
unlikely to undergo a material change over a short period of time
except in abnormal or revolutionary circumstances. In an
historical enquiry or in comparing one social system with another
of a different type, it is necessary to take account of the
manner in which changes in the subjective factors may affect the
propensity to consume. But, in general, we shall in what follows
take the subjective factors as given; and we shall assume that
the propensity to consume depends only on changes in the
objective factors.
II
The principal objective factors which influence the propensity
to consume appear to be the following:
(1) A change in the wage-unit.¾
Consumption (C)
is obviously much more a function of (in some sense) real income
than of money-income. In a given state of technique and tastes
and of social conditions determining the distribution of income,
a man's real income will rise and fall with the amount of his
command over labour-units, i.e. with the amount of his income
measured in wage-units; though when the aggregate volume of
output changes, his real income will (owing [p.92] to the operation of decreasing returns) rise less than in
proportion to his income measured in wage-units. As a first
approximation, therefore, we can reasonably assume that, if the
wage-unit changes, the expenditure on consumption corresponding
to a given level of employment will, like prices, change in the
same proportion; though in some circumstances we may have to make
an allowance for the possible reactions on aggregate consumption
of the change in the distribution of a given real income between
entrepreneurs and rentiers resulting from a change in the
wage-unit. Apart from this, we have already allowed for changes
in the wage-unit by defining the propensity to consume in terms
of income measured in terms of wage-units.
(2) A change in the difference between income
and net income.¾ We have shown above that the amount of
consumption depends on net income rather than on income, since it
is, by definition, his net income that a man has primarily in
mind when he is deciding his scale of consumption. In a given
situation there may be a somewhat stable relationship between the
two, in the sense that there will be a function uniquely relating
different levels of income to the corresponding levels of net
income. If, however, this should not be the case, such part of
any change in income as is not reflected in net income must be
neglected since it will have no effect on consumption; and,
similarly, a change in net income, not reflected in income, must
be allowed for. Save in exceptional circumstances, however, I
doubt the practical importance of this factor. We will return to
a fuller discussion of the effect on consumption of the
difference between income and net income in the fourth section of
this chapter.
(3) Windfall changes in capital-values not
allowed for in calculating net income.¾ These are of much more
importance in modifying the propensity to consume, since they
will bear no stable or regular relationship to the amount of
income. The consumption of the [p.93] wealth-owning class may be extremely susceptible to unforeseen
changes in the money-value of its wealth. This should be
classified amongst the major factors capable of causing
short-period changes in the propensity to consume.
(4) Changes in the rate of time-discounting, i.e.
in the ratio of exchange between present goods and future
goods.¾ This is not quite the same thing as the rate of
interest, since it allows for future changes in the purchasing
power of money in so far as these are foreseen. Account has also
to be taken of all kinds of risks, such as the prospect of not
living to enjoy the future goods or of confiscatory taxation. As
an approximation, however, we can identify this with the rate of
interest.
The influence of this factor on the rate of spending out of a
given income is open to a good deal of doubt. For the classical
theory of the rate of interest,[1]
which was based on the idea that the rate of interest was the
factor which brought the supply and demand for savings into
equilibrium, it was convenient to suppose that expenditure on
consumption is cet. par. negatively sensitive to changes
in the rate of interest, so that any rise in the rate of interest
would appreciably diminish consumption. It has long been
recognised, however, that the total effect of changes in the rate of interest on the readiness to spend on present consumption is
complex and uncertain, being dependent on conflicting tendencies,
since some of the subjective motives towards saving will be more
easily satisfied if the rate of interest rises, whilst others
will be weakened. Over a long period substantial changes in the
rate of interest probably tend to modify social habits
considerably, thus affecting the subjective propensity to spend¾though in which direction it would be hard
to say, except in the light of actual experience. The usual type
of short-period fluctuation in the rate of interest is not
likely, however, to have much direct influence on spending either
way. [p.94] There are not many people who will alter their way of living
because the rate of interest has fallen from 5 to 4 per cent, if
their aggregate income is the same as before. Indirectly there
may be more effects, though not all in the same direction.
Perhaps the most important influence, operating through changes
in the rate of interest, on the readiness to spend out of a given
income, depends on the effect of these changes on the
appreciation or depreciation in the price of securities and other
assets. For if a man is enjoying a windfall increment in the
value of his capital, it is natural that his motives towards
current spending should be strengthened, even though in terms of
income his capital is worth no more than before; and weakened if
he is suffering capital losses. But this indirect influence we
have allowed for already under (3) above. Apart from this, the
main conclusion suggested by experience is, I think, that the
short-period influence of the rate of interest on individual
spending out of a given income is secondary and relatively
unimportant, except, perhaps, where unusually large changes are
in question. When the rate of interest falls very low indeed, the
increase in the ratio between an annuity purchasable for a given
sum and the annual interest on that sum may, however, provide an
important source of negative saving by encouraging the practice
of providing for old age by the purchase of an annuity.
The abnormal situation, where the propensity to consume may be
sharply affected by the development of extreme uncertainty
concerning the future and what it may bring forth, should also,
perhaps, be classified under this heading.
(5) Changes in fiscal policy.¾ In so far as
the inducement to the individual to save depends on the future
return which he expects, it clearly depends not only on the rate
of interest but on the fiscal policy of the Government. Income
taxes, especially when they discriminate against "unearned"
income, taxes on [p.95] capital-profits, death-duties and the like are as relevant as
the rate of interest; whilst the range of possible changes in
fiscal policy may be greater, in expectation at least, than for
the rate of interest itself. If fiscal policy is used as a
deliberate instrument for the more equal distribution of incomes,
its effect in increasing the propensity to consume is, of course,
all the greater. [1]
We must also take account of the effect on the aggregate
propensity to consume of government sinking funds for the
discharge of debt paid for out of ordinary taxation. For these
represent a species of corporate saving, so that a policy of
substantial sinking funds must be regarded in given circumstances
as reducing the propensity to consume. It is for this reason that
a change-over from a policy of Government borrowing to the
opposite policy of providing sinking funds (or vice versa)
is capable of causing a severe contraction (or marked expansion)
of effective demand.
(6) Changes in expectations of the relation
between the present and the future level of income.¾
We must
catalogue this factor for the sake of formal completeness. But,
whilst it may affect considerably a particular individual's
propensity to consume, it is likely to average out for the
community as a whole. Moreover, it is a matter about which there
is, as a rule, too much uncertainty for it to exert much
influence.
We are left therefore, with the conclusion that in a given
situation the propensity to consume may be considered a fairly
stable function, provided that we have eliminated changes in the
wage-unit in terms of money. Windfall changes in capital-values
will be capable of changing the propensity to consume, and
substantial [p.96] changes in the rate of interest and in fiscal policy may make
some difference; but the other objective factors which might
affect it, whilst they must not be overlooked, are not likely to
be important in ordinary circumstances.
The fact that, given the general economic situation, the
expenditure on consumption in terms of the wage-unit depends in
the main, on the volume of output and employment is the
justification for summing up the other factors in the portmanteau
function "propensity to consume". For whilst the other factors
are capable of varying (and this must not be forgotten), the
aggregate income measured in terms of the wage-unit is, as a
rule, the principal variable upon which the
consumption-constituent of the aggregate demand function will
depend.
III
Granted, then, that the propensity to consume is a fairly
stable function so that, as a rule, the amount of aggregate
consumption mainly depends on the amount of aggregate income
(both measured in terms of wage-units), changes in the propensity
itself being treated as a secondary influence, what is the normal
shape of this function?
The fundamental psychological law, upon which we are entitled
to depend with great confidence both a priori from our
knowledge of human nature and from the detailed facts of
experience, is that men are disposed, as a rule and on the
average, to increase their consumption as their income increases,
but not by as much as the increase in their income. That is to
say, if Cw is the amount of consumption
and Yw is income (both measured in
wage-units) DCw
has the same sign as DYw
but is smaller in amount, i.e. dCw/dYw
is positive and less than unity.[p.97]
This is especially the case where we have short periods in
view, as in the case of the so-called cyclical fluctuations of
employment during which habits, as distinct from more permanent
psychological propensities, are not given time enough to adapt
themselves to changed objective circumstances. For a man's
habitual standard of life usually has the first claim on his
income, and he is apt to save the difference which discovers
itself between his actual income and the expense of his habitual
standard; or, if he does adjust his expenditure to changes in his
income, he will over short periods do so imperfectly. Thus a
rising income will often be accompanied by increased saving, and
a falling income by decreased saving, on a greater scale at first
than subsequently.
But, apart from short-period changes in the level of
income, it is also obvious that a higher absolute level of income
will tend, as a rule, to widen the gap between income and
consumption. For the satisfaction of the immediate primary needs
of a man and his family is usually a stronger motive than the
motives towards accumulation, which only acquire effective sway
when a margin of comfort has been attained. These reasons will
lead, as a rule, to a greater proportion of income being
saved as real income increases. But whether or not a greater
proportion is saved, we take it as a fundamental psychological
rule of any modern community that, when its real income is
increased, it will not increase its consumption by an equal absolute
amount, so that a greater absolute amount must be saved,
unless a large and unusual change is occurring at the same time
in other factors. As we shall show subsequently,[1]
the stability of the economic system essentially depends on this
rule prevailing in practice. This means that, if employment and
hence aggregate income increase, not all the additional
employment will be required to satisfy the needs of additional
consumption. [p.98]
On the other hand, a decline in income due to a decline in the
level of employment, if it goes far, may even cause consumption
to exceed income not only by some individuals and institutions
using up the financial reserves which they have accumulated in
better times, but also by the Government, which will be liable,
willingly or unwillingly, to run into a budgetary deficit or will
provide unemployment relief; for example, out of borrowed money.
Thus, when employment falls to a low level, aggregate consumption
will decline by a smaller amount than that by which real income
has declined, by reason both of the habitual behaviour of
individuals and also of the probable policy of governments; which
is the explanation why a new position of equilibrium can usually
be reached within a modest range of fluctuation. Otherwise a fall
in employment and income, once started, might proceed to extreme
lengths.
This simple principle leads, it will be seen, to the same
conclusion as before, namely, that employment can only increase pari
passu with an increase in investment; unless, indeed, there
is a change in the propensity to consume. For since consumers
will spend less than the increase in aggregate supply price when
employment is increased, the increased employment will prove
unprofitable unless there is an increase in investment to fill
the gap.
IV
We must not underestimate the importance of the fact already
mentioned above that, whereas employment is a function of the
expected consumption and the expected investment, consumption is,
cet. par., a function of net income, i.e. of net
investment (net income being equal to consumption plus net
investment). In other words, the larger the financial provision
which it is thought necessary to make before reckoning net in-[p.99]come, the less favourable to consumption, and therefore to
employment, will a given level of investment prove to be.
When the whole of this financial provision (or supplementary
cost) is in fact currently expended in the upkeep of the already
existing capital equipment, this point is not likely to be
overlooked. But when the financial provision exceeds the
actual expenditure on current upkeep, the practical results of
this in its effect on employment are not always appreciated. For
the amount of this excess neither directly gives rise to current
investment nor is available to pay for consumption. It has,
therefore, to be balanced by new investment, the demand for which
has arisen quite independently of the current wastage of old
equipment against which the financial provision is being made;
with the result that the new investment available to provide
current income is correspondingly diminished and a more intense
demand for new investment is necessary to make possible a given
level of employment. Moreover, much the same considerations apply
to the allowance for wastage included in user cost, in so far as
the wastage is not actually made good.
Take a house which continues to be habitable until it is
demolished or abandoned. If a certain sum is written off its
value out of the annual rent paid by the tenants, which the
landlord neither spends on upkeep nor regards as net income
available for consumption, this provision, whether it is a part
of U or of V; constitutes a drag on employment all
through the life of the house, suddenly made good in a lump when
the house has to be rebuilt.
In a stationary economy all this might not be worth
mentioning, since in each year the depreciation allowances in
respect of old houses would be exactly offset by the new houses
built in replacement of those reaching the end of their lives in
that year. But such factors may be serious in a non-static
economy, especially [p.100] during a period which immediately succeeds a lively burst of
investment in long-lived capital. For in such circumstances a
very large proportion of the new items of investment may be
absorbed by the larger financial provisions made by entrepreneurs
in respect of existing capital equipment, upon the repairs and
renewal of which, though it is wearing out with time, the date
has not yet arrived for spending anything approaching the full
financial provision which is being set aside; with the result
that incomes cannot rise above a level which is low enough to
correspond with a low aggregate of net investment. Thus sinking
funds, etc., are apt to withdraw spending power from the consumer
long before the demand for expenditure on replacements (which
such provisions are anticipating) comes into play; i.e. they
diminish the current effective demand and only increase it in the
year in which the replacement is actually made. If the effect of
this is aggravated by "financial prudence", i.e. by its being
thought advisable to "write off" the initial cost more rapidly
than the equipment actually wears out, the cumulative result may
be very serious indeed.
In the United States, for example, by 1929 the rapid capital
expansion of the previous five years had led cumulatively to the
setting up of sinking funds and depreciation allowances, in
respect of plant which did not need replacement, on so huge a
scale that an enormous volume of entirely new investment was
required merely to absorb these financial provisions; and it
became almost hopeless to find still more new investment on a
sufficient scale to provide for such new saving as a wealthy
community in full employment would be disposed to set aside. This
factor alone was probably sufficient to cause a slump. And,
furthermore, since "financial prudence" of this kind continued to
be exercised through the slump by those great corporations which
were still in a position to afford it, it offered a serious
obstacle to early recovery.[p.101]
Or again, in Great Britain at the present time (1935) the
substantial amount of house-building and of other new investments
since the war has led to an amount of sinking funds being set up
much in excess of any present requirements for expenditure on
repairs and renewals, a tendency which has been accentuated,
where the investment has been made by local authorities and
public boards, by the principles of "sound" finance which often
require sinking funds sufficient to write off the initial cost
some time before replacement will actually fall due; with the
result that even if private individuals were ready to spend the
whole of their net incomes it would be a severe task to restore
full employment in the face of this heavy volume of statutory
provision by public and semi-public authorities, entirely
dissociated from any corresponding new investment. The sinking
funds of local authorities now stand, I think,[1]
at an annual figure of more than half the amount which these
authorities are spending on the whole of their new
developments. [2] Yet it is not certain that the Ministry of Health are aware, when
they insist on stiff sinking funds by local authorities, how much
they may be aggravating the problem of unemployment. In the case
of advances by building societies to help an individual to build
his own house, the desire to be clear of debt more rapidly than
the house actually deteriorates may stimulate the house-owner to
save more than he otherwise would;¾though
this factor should be classified, perhaps, as diminishing the
propensity to consume directly rather than through its effect on
net income. In actual figures, repayments of mortgages advanced
by building societies, which amounted to £24,000,000 in 1925,
had risen to [p.102] £68,000,000 by 1933, as compared with new advances of
£103,000,000; and to-day the repayments are probably still
higher.
That it is investment, rather than net investment, which
emerges from the statistics of output, is brought out forcibly
and naturally in Mr. Colin Clark's
National Income, 1924-1931. He also shows what a large
proportion depreciation, etc., normally bears to the value of
investment. For example, he estimates that in Great Britain, over
the years 1928-1931, [1]
the investment and the net investment were as follows, though his
gross investment is probably somewhat greater than my investment,
inasmuch as it may include a part of user cost, and it is not
clear how closely his "net investment" corresponds to my
definition of this term:
|
(£ million) |
|
1928 |
1929 |
1930 |
1931 |
Gross Investment-Output |
791 |
731 |
620 |
482 |
"Value of physical wasting of old capital" |
433 |
435 |
437 |
439 |
Net Investment |
358 |
296 |
183 |
43 |
Mr. Kuznets has arrived at much the same conclusion in
compiling the statistics of the Gross Capital Formation (as
he calls what I call investment) in the United States, 1919-1933. The physical fact, to which the
statistics of output correspond, is inevitably the gross, and not
the net, investment. Mr. Kuznets has also discovered the
difficulties in passing from gross investment to net investment. "The difficulty", he writes,
"of passing from gross to net
capital formation, that is, the difficulty of correcting for the
consumption of existing durable commodities, is not only in the
lack of data. The very concept of annual consumption of
commodities that last over a number of years suffers [p.103] from
ambiguity". He falls back, therefore, "on the assumption that the allowance for depreciation and depletion
on the books of business firms describes correctly the volume of
consumption of already existing, finished durable goods used by
business firms".
On the other hand, he attempts no deduction at all in respect of
houses and other durable commodities in the hands of individuals.
His very interesting results for the United States can be
summarised as follows:
|
(Millions of Dollars) |
|
1925 |
1926 |
1927 |
1928 |
1929 |
Gross capital formation (after
allowing for net change in business inventories)
|
30,706 |
33,571 |
31,157 |
33,934 |
34,491 |
Entrepreneurs' servicing, repairs,
maintenance, depreciation and depletion |
7,685 |
8,288 |
8,223 |
8,481 |
9,010 |
Net capital formation (on Mr Kuznets'
definition) |
23,021 |
25,283 |
22,934 |
25,453 |
25,481 |
|
(Millions of Dollars) |
|
1930 |
1931 |
1932 |
1933 |
Gross capital formation (after
allowing for net change in business inventories)
|
27,538 |
18,721 |
7,780 |
14,879 |
Entrepreneurs' servicing, repairs,
maintenance, depreciation and depletion |
8,502 |
7,623 |
6,543 |
8,204 |
Net capital formation (on Mr Kuznets'
definition) |
19,036 |
11,098 |
1,237 |
6,675 |
These references are taken from a Bulletin (No. 52) of the National Bureau of
Economic Research, giving preliminary results of Mr. Kuznets' forthcoming book.
[p.104]
Several facts emerge with prominence from this table. Net
capital formation was very steady over the quinquennium 1925-1929, with only a 10 per cent increase in the latter part of the upward movement. The
deduction for entrepreneurs' repairs, maintenance, depreciation
and depletion remained at a high figure even at the bottom of the
slump. But Mr Kuznets' method must surely lead to too low an
estimate of the annual increase in depreciation, etc.; for he
puts the latter at less than 1½ per cent per annum of the new
net capital formation. Above all, net capital formation suffered
an appalling collapse after 1929, falling in 1932 to a figure no
less than 95 per cent below the average of the
quinquennium 1925-1929.
The above is, to some extent, a digression. But it is
important to emphasise the magnitude of the deduction which has
to be made from the income of a society, which already possesses
a large stock of capital, before we arrive at the net income
which is ordinarily available for consumption. For if we overlook
this, we may underestimate the heavy drag on the propensity to
consume which exists even in conditions where the public is ready
to consume a very large proportion of its net income.
Consumption¾to repeat the obvious¾is the sole end and object of all economic
activity. Opportunities for employment are necessarily limited by
the extent of aggregate demand. Aggregate demand can be derived
only from present consumption or from present provision for
future consumption. The consumption for which we can profitably
provide in advance cannot be pushed indefinitely into the future.
We cannot, as a community, provide for future consumption by
financial expedients but only by current physical output. In so
far as our social and business organisation separates financial
provision for the future from physical provision for the future
so that efforts to secure the former [p.105] do not necessarily carry the
latter with them, financial prudence will be liable to diminish
aggregate demand and thus impair well-being, as there are many
examples to testify. The greater, moreover, the consumption for which
we have provided in advance, the more difficult it is to find
something further to provide for in advance, and the greater our
dependence on present consumption as a source of demand. Yet the
larger our incomes, the greater, unfortunately, is the margin
between our incomes and our consumption. So, failing some novel
expedient, there is, as we shall see, no answer to the riddle,
except that there must be sufficient unemployment to keep us so
poor that our consumption falls short of our income by no more
than the equivalent of the physical provision for future
consumption which it pays to produce to-day.
Or look at the matter thus. Consumption is satisfied partly by
objects produced currently and partly by objects produced
previously, i.e. by disinvestment. To the extent that consumption
is satisfied by the latter, there is a contraction of current
demand, since to that extent a part of current expenditure fails
to find its way back as a part of net income. Contrariwise
whenever an object is produced within the period with a view to
satisfying consumption subsequently, an expansion of current
demand is set up. Now all capital-investment is destined to
result, sooner or later, in capital-disinvestment. Thus the
problem of providing that new capital-investment shall always
outrun capital-disinvestment sufficiently to fill the gap between
net income and consumption, presents a problem which is
increasingly difficult as capital increases. New
capital-investment can only take place in excess of current
capital-disinvestment if future expenditure on consumption
is expected to increase. Each time we secure to-day's equilibrium
by increased investment we are aggravating the difficulty of
securing equilibrium to-morrow. A diminished propensity to
consume to-day can only be [p.106] accommodated to the public advantage
if an increased propensity to consume is expected to exist some
day. We are reminded of "The Fable of the
Bees"¾the gay of to-morrow are absolutely indispensable to provide a raison
d'être for the grave of to-day.
It is a curious thing,
worthy of mention, that the popular mind seems only to be aware
of this ultimate perplexity where public investment is
concerned, as in the case of road-building and house-building and
the like. It is commonly urged as an objection to schemes for
raising employment by investment under the auspices of public
authority that it is laying up trouble for the future. "What will
you do," it is asked, "when you have built all the houses and
roads and town halls and electric grids and water supplies and so
forth which the stationary population of the future can be
expected to require?" But it is not so easily understood that the
same difficulty applies to private investment and to industrial
expansion; particularly to the latter, since it is much easier to
see an early satiation of the demand for new factories and plant
which absorb individually but little money, than of the demand
for dwelling-houses.
The obstacle to a clear understanding is, in these examples,
much the same as in many academic discussions of capital, namely,
an inadequate appreciation of the fact that capital is not a
self-subsistent entity existing apart from consumption. On the
contrary, every weakening in the propensity to consume regarded
as a permanent habit must weaken the demand for capital as well
as the demand for consumption.
Footnotes: [p.93] 1 - Cf.
Chapter 14 below. [back to text]
[p.95] 1 - It may be mentioned, in
passing, that the effect of fiscal policy on the growth of wealth has been the
subject of an important misunderstanding which, however, we cannot discuss
adequately without the assistance of the theory of the rate of interest to be
given in Book IV. [back to text]
[p.97] 1 - Cf. p.251
below. [back to text]
[p.101] 1 - The actual figures are
deemed of so little interest that they are only published two years or more in
arrear. [back to text]
[p.101] 2 - In the year ending March
31, 1930, local authorities spent £87,000,000 on capital account, of which
£37,000,000 was provided by sinking funds, etc., in respect of previous capital
expenditure; in the year endind March 31, 1933, the figures were
£81,000,000 and £46,000,000. [back to text]
[p.102] 1 - Op. cit. pp.117
and 138. [back to text]
|